Colloquium Vervoersplanologisch S peurwerk 7995



Vergelijkbare documenten
Colloquium Vervoersplanologisch

Vervoersplanologisch. Colloquium. Speurwerk n CK n INNOVATIE IN VERKEER EN VERVOER. Deel 3. bijdragen van het colloquium.

Travel Survey Questionnaires

Socio-economic situation of long-term flexworkers

Esther Lee-Varisco Matt Zhang

Het Effect van Verschil in Sociale Invloed van Ouders en Vrienden op het Alcoholgebruik van Adolescenten.

Colloquium Vervoersplanologisch Speurwerk 1990

ANGSTSTOORNISSEN EN HYPOCHONDRIE: DIAGNOSTIEK EN BEHANDELING (DUTCH EDITION) FROM BOHN STAFLEU VAN LOGHUM

z x 1 x 2 x 3 x 4 s 1 s 2 s 3 rij rij rij rij

Opgave 2 Geef een korte uitleg van elk van de volgende concepten: De Yield-to-Maturity of a coupon bond.

FOR DUTCH STUDENTS! ENGLISH VERSION NEXT PAGE. Toets Inleiding Kansrekening 1 8 februari 2010

Impact en disseminatie. Saskia Verhagen Franka vd Wijdeven

Aim of this presentation. Give inside information about our commercial comparison website and our role in the Dutch and Spanish energy market

Designing climate proof urban districts

Concept of Feedback. P.S. Gandhi Mechanical Engineering IIT Bombay

Pesten onder Leerlingen met Autisme Spectrum Stoornissen op de Middelbare School: de Participantrollen en het Verband met de Theory of Mind.

Researchcentrum voor Onderwijs en Arbeidsmarkt The role of mobility in higher education for future employability

De Samenhang tussen Dagelijkse Stress en Depressieve Symptomen en de Mediërende Invloed van Controle en Zelfwaardering

Impacts Tallinn 31 st may 2018 Senta Modder - Germa Bakker

Invloed van het aantal kinderen op de seksdrive en relatievoorkeur

Intercultural Mediation through the Internet Hans Verrept Intercultural mediation and policy support unit

Chapter 4 Understanding Families. In this chapter, you will learn

Relatie tussen Persoonlijkheid, Opleidingsniveau, Leeftijd, Geslacht en Korte- en Lange- Termijn Seksuele Strategieën

Add the standing fingers to get the tens and multiply the closed fingers to get the units.

RECEPTEERKUNDE: PRODUCTZORG EN BEREIDING VAN GENEESMIDDELEN (DUTCH EDITION) FROM BOHN STAFLEU VAN LOGHUM

SAMPLE 11 = + 11 = + + Exploring Combinations of Ten + + = = + + = + = = + = = 11. Step Up. Step Ahead

De grondbeginselen der Nederlandsche spelling / Regeling der spelling voor het woordenboek der Nederlandsche taal (Dutch Edition)

MyDHL+ Van Non-Corporate naar Corporate

Understanding and being understood begins with speaking Dutch

Appendix A: List of variables with corresponding questionnaire items (in English) used in chapter 2

COGNITIEVE DISSONANTIE EN ROKERS COGNITIVE DISSONANCE AND SMOKERS

(1) De hoofdfunctie van ons gezelschap is het aanbieden van onderwijs. (2) Ons gezelschap is er om kunsteducatie te verbeteren

Group work to study a new subject.

Ben ik Lid van de Groep? Ervaren inclusie als Moderator van de Relatie tussen Procedurele Rechtvaardigheid en Organizational Citizenship Behavior.

Emotionele Arbeid, de Dutch Questionnaire on Emotional Labor en. Bevlogenheid

Beïnvloedt Gentle Teaching Vaardigheden van Begeleiders en Companionship en Angst bij Verstandelijk Beperkte Cliënten?

Angststoornissen en hypochondrie: Diagnostiek en behandeling (Dutch Edition) Click here if your download doesn"t start automatically

Ontpopping. ORGACOM Thuis in het Museum

Activant Prophet 21. Prophet 21 Version 12.0 Upgrade Information

de Rol van Persoonlijkheid Eating: the Role of Personality

Falende Interpretatie? De Samenhang van Faalangst met Interpretatiebias

Summary 124

Ontwerpen van een variabele belasting om te meten aan zonnepanelen

Differences in stress and stress reactivity between highly educated stay-at-home and working. mothers with spouse and young children

HANDBOEK HARTFALEN (DUTCH EDITION) FROM BOHN STAFLEU VAN LOGHUM

FOR DUTCH STUDENTS! ENGLISH VERSION NEXT PAGE

Ir. Herman Dijk Ministry of Transport, Public Works and Water Management

Verschillen in het Gebruik van Geheugenstrategieën en Leerstijlen. Differences in the Use of Memory Strategies and Learning Styles

De Relatie tussen Betrokkenheid bij Pesten en Welbevinden en de Invloed van Sociale Steun en. Discrepantie

2010 Integrated reporting

NETWORK CHARTER. #ResourceEfficiency

Behandeleffecten. in Forensisch Psychiatrisch Center de Rooyse Wissel. Treatment effects in. Forensic Psychiatric Centre de Rooyse Wissel

Werk in balans. verloop bij verzorgenden en verpleegkundigen. Work in balance. turnover of nurses and health-care workers.

Ouderlijke Controle en Angst bij Kinderen, de Invloed van Psychologische Flexibiliteit

Een vrouw, een kind en azijn (Dutch Edition)

CORPORATE BRANDING AND SOCIAL MEDIA: KEY FINDINGS FOR DUTCH CONSUMERS Theo Araujo

Relatie tussen Cyberpesten en Opvoeding. Relation between Cyberbullying and Parenting. D.J.A. Steggink. Eerste begeleider: Dr. F.

Puzzle. Fais ft. Afrojack Niveau 3a Song 6 Lesson A Worksheet. a Lees de omschrijvingen. Zet de Engelse woorden in de puzzel.

Longitudinal Driving Behaviour At Incidents And The Influence Of Emotions. Raymond Hoogendoorn

De Relatie tussen Werkdruk, Pesten op het Werk, Gezondheidsklachten en Verzuim

AN URBAN PLAYGROUND AFSTUDEERPROJECT

1. In welk deel van de wereld ligt Nederland? 2. Wat betekent Nederland?

Academisch schrijven Inleiding

B1 Woordkennis: Spelling

Preschool Kindergarten

The Dutch mortgage market at a cross road? The problematic relationship between supply of and demand for residential mortgages

PROJECT INFORMATION Building De Meerlanden Nieuweweg 65 in Hoofddorp

Competencies atlas. Self service instrument to support jobsearch. Naam auteur

Innovative SUMP-Process in Northeast-Brabant

THE ART OF INTEGRATION Rens Verweij, VICE Sophie Schade, Kantar Millward Brown

Cycling in The Netherlands & The Hague

FOR DUTCH STUDENTS! ENGLISH VERSION NEXT PAGE

Fysieke Activiteit bij 50-plussers. The Relationship between Self-efficacy, Intrinsic Motivation and. Physical Activity among Adults Aged over 50

Sport participation and the role of sport facilities in the Netherlands

FOR DUTCH STUDENTS! ENGLISH VERSION NEXT PAGE. Toets Inleiding Kansrekening 1 7 februari 2011

Het executief en het sociaal cognitief functioneren bij licht verstandelijk. gehandicapte jeugdigen. Samenhang met emotionele- en gedragsproblemen

Effecten van een op MBSR gebaseerde training van. hospicemedewerkers op burnout, compassionele vermoeidheid en

Running Head: SMARTPHONE>ACTIVITEITEN>DETACHMENT>HERSTEL

It s all about the money Group work

Persoonlijke informatie / Personal information

Seksdrive, Stresscoping en Extrinsieke Ambitie : De Verschillen tussen Mannen en Vrouwen. Sexdrive, Stresscoping and Extrinsic Ambition :

CHROMA STANDAARDREEKS

Welkom. Digitale programma: #cmdag18. Dagvoorzitter Prof. dr. Arjan van Weele NEVI hoogleraar inkoopmanagement.

Topic 10-5 Meeting Children s Intellectual Needs

Verloop bij de Politie: de Rol van Procedurele en Interactionele Rechtvaardigheid en Commitment

De Samenhang tussen Dagelijkse Stress, Emotionele Intimiteit en Affect bij Partners met een. Vaste Relatie

Adherence aan HWO en meer bewegen

De Invloed van Innovatiekenmerken op de Intentie van Leerkrachten. een Lespakket te Gebruiken om Cyberpesten te Voorkomen of te.

Sustainable Urban Mobility Plan Rotterdam, april 2016

Empowerment project. Driejarig project van Rotaryclub Rhenen-Veenendaal

International Leiden Leadership Programme

ALGORITMIEK: answers exercise class 7

Keuzetwijfels in de Emerging Adulthood rondom Studie- en Partnerkeuze. in Relatie tot Depressie

Zo werkt het in de apotheek (Basiswerk AG) (Dutch Edition)

GOVERNMENT NOTICE. STAATSKOERANT, 18 AUGUSTUS 2017 No NATIONAL TREASURY. National Treasury/ Nasionale Tesourie NO AUGUST

ARTIST. Petten 24 September More info:

FOR DUTCH STUDENTS! ENGLISH VERSION NEXT PAGE

BE Nanoregistry Annual Public Report

Bijlage 2: Informatie met betrekking tot goede praktijkvoorbeelden in Londen, het Verenigd Koninkrijk en Queensland

Transcriptie:

Colloquium Vervoersplanologisch S peurwerk 7995 Bundeling van bijdragen aan het colloquium gehouden te Rotterdam op 23-24 november 1995 Redactie H. J. Meurs E. J. Verroen Dee1 3

Kafiontwerp: Jos Ontwerp Studio, Breda

COLLOQUIUM VERVOERSPLANOLOGISCH SPEURWERK Het doe1 van het Colloquium Vervoersplanologisch Speurwerk is een ontmoetingsplaats te vormen waar nieuwe inzichten en ideeen met betrekking tot de vervoersplanning en de raakvlakken hiervan met de ruimtelijke planning worden gepresenteerd en besproken. De auteurs bezitten auteursrechten van hun bijdragen. Bestelling van boeken: Dit verslag, dat uit drie delen bestaat, kan worden besteld door overmaking van f 150,- op girorekening 58.06.21 ten name van de penningmeester van het Colloquium Vervoersplanologisch Speurwerk, Geerdinkhof 237, 1103 PZ Amsterdam, onder vermelding van TVS 1995 en de naam en adres van de besteller. Aanbevolen literatuurverwijzing: H.J. Meurs & E.J. Verroen (red.) Colloquium Vervoersplanologisch Speurwerk - 1995 - Decentralisatie van beleid: implicaties voor kennis en onderzoek, Delft, C.V.S., 1995. III

TRANSPORTATION PLANNING RESEARCH COLLOQUIUM The purpose of the Transportation Planning Research Colloquium is to provide a meeting ground for the presentation and discussion of new insights and ideas in the field of transportation and its relationship with spatial planning. Authors retain all rights in their papers. Orders for books: Copies of this publication CVS-I 995, which exists of three volumes, can be ordered from the treasurer of the Transportation Planning Research Colloquium, Geerdinkhof 237, NL-1103 PZ Amsterdam, The Netherlands. Suggested citation: H.J. Meurs & E.J. Verroen (red.) Colloquium Vervoersplanologisch Speurwerk - 1995 - Decentralisatie van beleid: implicaties voor kennis en onderzoek, Deb?, C.V.S., 1995. IV

LIST OF PUBLISHED PROCEEDINGS OF THE PREVIOUS COLLOQUIA 1. P.H.L. Bovy et al (red.) Colloquium Vervoersplanologisch Speurwerk -1974- modellen en methoden in de vervoersplanologie. 2. F. le Clercq et al (red.) Colloquium Vervoersplanologisch Speurwerk -1975- praktijk en model in de vervoersplanning. 3. J.P.J.M. van Est et al (red.) Colloquium Vervoersplanologisch Speurwerk -1976- planevaluatie, vervoersmodellen en ruimtelijk keuzegedrag. 4. G.R.M. Jansen et al (red.) Colloquium Vervoersplanologisch Speurwerk - 1977- veranderingen in en om vervoersplanologisch onderzoek. 5. G.R.M. Jansen et al (red.) New developments in modelling travel demand and urban systems: some results of recent Dutch research. Famborough, Saxon House, 1979 (alleen via boekhandel). 6. F. le Clercq et al (red.) Colloquium Vervoersplanologisch Speurwerk -1979- vervoersstudies, -modellen en methoden. Deb?, 1979. 7. P.H.L. Bovy et al (red.) Colloquium Vervoersplanologisch Speurwerk -1980- mobiliteit, ruimtelijke interactie en vervoerssysteemgebruik. Delft. 1980. V

8. C.J. Ruijgrok & J.P.J.M. van Est (red.) Colloquium Vervoersplanologisch Speurwerk - 198 I- nieuwe tendensen in de vervoersplanologie. Delft, 1981. 9. J.G. Smit & F. le Clercq (red.) Colloquium Vervoersplanologisch Speurwerk -1982- openbaar vervoer, kompakte stad en mobiliteit. Delft, 1982. 10. P.H.L. Bovy (red.) Colloquium Vervoersplanologisch Speurwerk -1983- Transportation and stagnation; challenges for planning and research (2 volumes). Delft, 1983. 11. G.R.M. Jansen et al (red.) Transportation and Mobility in an Era of Transition Elsevier/North-Holland, 1985 (alleen via de boekhandel). 12. J.P. van Est (red.) Colloquium Vervoersplanologisch Speurwerk -1984- Mobiliteit in beweging (2 delen). Delhi, 1984. 13. F. le Clercq (red.) Colloquium Vervoersplanologisch Speurwerk - 1985- Dynamiek in verkeer en mobiliteit (2 delen). Deli?, 1985. VI

14. G.R.M. Jansen (red.) Colloquium Vervoersplanologisch Speurwerk -1986- Mobiliteit, transport en technologische vernieuwing (2 delen). Delft, 1986. 15. E.J. Verroen (red.) Colloquium Vervoersplanologisch Speurwerk -1987-8 miljoen auto s in 2010 (3 delen). Delft, 1987. 16. P.M. Blok (red.) Colloquium Vervoersplanologisch Speurwerk -1988- Nederland in nota s, strategie en pragmatisme en beleid en onderzoek (3 delen). Delhi, 1988. 17. H.J. Meurs (red.) Colloquium Vervoersplanologisch Speurwerk - 1989- Vervoerbeleid tussen rand en stad, naar een integrale aanpak op regionaal niveau (3 delen). Delft. 1989. 18. J.M. Jager (red.) Colloquium Vervoersplanologisch Speurwerk - 1990- Meten-modelleren-monitoren (2 delen). Delft. 1990. 19. P. T. Tanja (red.) Colloquium Vervoersplanologisch Speurwerk -1991- De prijs van mobiliteit en van mobiliteitsbeperking (3 delen). Delft, 1991. VII

20. P.M. Blok (red.) Colloquium Vervoersplanologisch Speurwerk - 1992- Innovatie in Verkeer en Vervoer (3 delen). Deli?, 1992. 21. Th.A.M. Reijs & P.T. Tanja (red.) Colloquium Vervoersplanologisch Speurwerk - 1993- Grenzen aan de vervoersplanologie (3 delen). Delft, 1993. 22. J.M. Jager (red.) Colloquium Vervoersplanologisch Speurwerk - 1994- Implementatie van beleid. De moeizame weg van voomemen naar actie (3 delen). Delft, 1994. De publikaties (met uitzondering van de nummers 5 en 11) kunnen worden besteld door overmaking van het bijbehorende bedrag op girorekening 58.0621 ten name van de penningmeester van het Colloquium Vervoersplanologisch Speurwerk, Geerdinkhof 237, 1103 PZ Amsterdam, onder vermelding van CVS, jaartal en nummer, en de naam en het adres van de besteller. Het over te maken bedrag is voor de publikaties: - 1 t/m 8 f 25,-- - 9 t/m 14 f 55,-- - 15 t/m 17 f 85,-- - 18 f 75,-- - 19 en 20 f 120,-- - 21 en 22 f 150,-- Copies of these publications can be ordered from the treasurer of the Transportation Planning Research Colloquium, Geerdinkhof 237, NL-I 103 PZ Amsterdam, The Netherlands. VIII

Voor u liggen de in drie delen gebundelde bijdragen aan het twee-en-twintigste Colloquium Vervoersplanologisch Speurwerk (CVS). Het congres is gepland op 23 en 24 november 1995 te Rotterdam. Het Colloquium heel? een drietal doelstellingen: 1. Het presenteren en verspreiden van recent speurwerk op het gebied van vervoersplanning, inclusief de raakvlakken daarvan met ruimtelijke planning, aan collega-onderzoekers en beleidsvoorbereiders. 2. Het creeren van een forum waar dit speurwerk ter discussie wordt gesteld. 3. Het vormen van een ontmoetingsplaats, waar onderzoek en beleid kunnen samenkomen. De vorm van het Colloquium is gericht op actieve participatie van alle deelnemers. Iedere deelnemer dient een schriftelijke bijdrage in, of in de vorm van een paper, of via een discussiebijdrage die vooraf op papier wordt gezet. Het onderwerp van de bijdrage is in principe bij, maar moet we1 binnen het vervoersplanologische thema van het congres vallen. Daamaast wordt ieder jaar door de organisatie een thema gekozen: waarop deelnemers nadrukkelijk worden uitgenodigd een bijdrage in te dienen. Het centrale thema voor het CVS 1995 luidt: DECENTRALISATIE VAN BELEID: Implicaties voor kennis en ondenoek In het vervoersbeleid wordt meer en meer de nadruk gelegd op uitwerking en implementatie op regionaal en lokaal niveau. Het rijk wil zich meer beperken tot het formuleren van de hoofdlijnen en hecht veel belang aan een open dialoog met regionale betrokkenen. IX

Deze tendens tot decentralisatie leidt tot een veranderende kennis-behoefte. Daarbij staan twee vragen centraal. Allereerst speelt de vraag welke beleidskennis op welk schaalniveau nodig is. Meer dart tot nu toe zal het beleidsonderzoek er op gericht moeten zijn om de juiste kennis op het juiste niveau in te brengen. Voor de rijksoverheid zal bij de kennisopbouw enerzijds meer het accent komen te liggen op strategische vraagstukken, terwijl anderzijds meer aandacht zal uitgaan naar het aanbieden van kennis en informatie die de operationele besluitvorming in de regio kan ondersteunen. Daamaast zal meer aandacht moeten worden besteed aan de standaardisatie van onderzoeksmethoden voor de evaluatie en afweging van beleidsmaatregelen. Ten tweede gaat het om de vraag hoe deze beleidskennis beter kan worden ingebracht in de regionale beleidsdiscussies. Gesteld kan worden dat niet zozeer de aanwezigheid van kennis als we1 de toegankelijkheid ervan een steeds groter probleem vormt bij regionale beleidsdiscussies. Dit roept de vraag op hoe onderzoeksinzichten en -gegevens beter en begrijpelijker kunnen worden ontsloten zodat een meer direct gebruik bij de regionale beleidsvorming mogelijk wordt. Naast de organisatorische voorwaarden gaat het hier ook om het gebruik van moderne methoden en technieken voor kennisoverdracht en procesondersteuning, zoals decission support systemen, interfaces voor databestanden, informatiesystemen en gestructureerde (elektronische) discussie-technieken. Naast de onderwerpen die betrekking hebben op dit thema worden ook dit jaar weer veel andere onderwerpen op het CVS aan de orde gesteld. De thema-bijdragen zijn gebundeld in deel 1, de overige bijdragen in de delen 2 en 3. De organisatie van het CVS 1995 was in handen van ondergetekenden, die daarbij volledig a titre personnel optreden. Op deze plaats willen we graag onze dank uitspreken aan onze werkgevers:

- Adviesdienst Verkeer en Vervoer, Rotterdam. - AGV Adviesgroep voor Verkeer en Vervoer BV, Nieuwegein. - INRO Cenmnn voor Infrastructuur, Transport en Regionale Ontwikkeling, Delft. - MuConsult, UtrechtiAmersfoort. - BEA Bureau voor Economische Argumentatie, Hoofddorp. Een bijzonder woord van dank verdient Dick den Adel van de Technische Universiteit Delhi, vakgroep Stedebouwkunde. Hij droeg ook dit jaar weer zorg voor de vele praktische zaken, die de organisatie van de bijeenkomst en het samenstellen van de CVS-boeken vereist. Het bestuur van het CVS, Peter Blok Joke Jager Theo Reijs Pieter Tanja Henk Meurs Erik Verroen Arnoud Mouwen Delft, oktober 1995 XI

Voorwoord Inhoudsopgave Dee1 1 INHOUDSOPGAVE 1. Aardoom, N., J. van Ginkel & R. Runderkamp PADRE: een systeem voor afleiding van regionale mobiliteitsgrootheden. 2. Bruinsma, F., P. Nijkamp & G. Pepping Een baten-assessment van hoogwaardige stedelijke railinfrastructuur. 3. Buffing, A.H.M. & E.H. Poelstra Km-men de kleren van de keizer verdeeld worden over de regionale prinsen? 4. Evert, H.C. van & L.H. Immers Onderbouwing van het verkeers- en vervoerbeleid in de regio. 5. Fledderus, K. & M. Vanderschuren Verkeersongevallenrisico blijkt lager op Randstadniveau. 6. Geurs, K. Lokaal verkeers- en vervoerbeleid: effecten op intensiteiten en milieu. 7. Ginkel, J.C. van, S.P. Berrevoet & C.A.J. Wilbers Decentrale aansturing instandhouding hoofdwegeninfrastructuur: implicaties voor kennisbehoefie. 8. Gommers, M.J.P.F. Zeebereikbaarheid van het Noordzeekanaalgebied: Regionale en transporteconomische analyse. een decentraal aangepakt. 9. Kapoen, L., J. van Grinsven & J. Hoetelmans Verkeersonveiligheid in beeld. De bepaling van regionale verschillen in x\ verkeersonveiligheid. \ 10. Korbee, H., A. Hoogvorst & K. Kusters ii Het InfraLab-experiment in Noord-Brabant als marktplaats voor kennisuitwisseling. 11. Louisse, K. & H. van der Rest Modellen ondersteunen regionaai fietsbeleid. 1 21 41 49 65 87 107 121 135 153 173 XIII

,,/-l&/meurs, H., H. Flikkema & J. van der Waard Operationalisatie van bereikbaarheid (OBER). 13. Meurs, H., J. Tils & J. van der Waard Monitoring congestie. 14. Moritz, G., J. van der Waard & J. Exe1 Uitbreiding OVG en nieuwe toepassingsmogelijkheden. 15. Ploeg, G.C.P. van der & F. le Clercq Integrale en interactieve afweging: nieuwe eisen aan beleids- en besluitvorming rondom infrastructuur. 16. Rtihl, A. Gedeelde kennis is dubbele kennis. 17. Velde, D. van de & W. Veeneman Beste burgemeester, waar gaat deze lijn heen? Een prod&tie in 8 delen. 18. Witbreuk, M. Collectieve actie en regionaal verkeers- en vervoersbeleid. Dee1 2 19. Baggen, J.H. Duurzame mobiliteit in de Randstad in 2015: Scenarioanalyse m.b.v. een causaal padmodel. 20. Beek, P. van, N. Kalfs & M. Speulman Reconstructie van verplaatsingen in tijdsbestedingsonderzoek. 21. Benschop, J., E. van Berkum & L. Schoren Dynamische toedeling in de praktijk. 22. Bilderbeek, R., M. van Hagen & W. Korver Scenario s voor de chipcard in het personenverkeer en -vervoer van 2015. 23. Binsbergen, A. van Ontwikkelingen binnen het vervoersysteem. 24. Binsbergen, A. van & J. Visser Distributie in stedelijke gebieden ondergronds? 189 211 231 251 267 283 303 323 343 361 383 405 425 XIV

25. Boose, J. & B. van Wee Invloed van prijsmaatregelen op autobezit, en -gebruik, energiegebruik en emissies. 26. Bovy, P.H.L. & M. Tacken Behavioural reactions to traffic congestion. 27. Bozuwa, J., M. van den Bossche & A. t Hoen Het economisch belang van vrachtautostroken in Zuid-Holland. 28. Bruinsma, F., A. t Hoen & J. Klooster Handboek economische effecten infrastructuur: een nieuw hulpmiddel bij projectstudies. 29. Dings, J.M.W. & J.H.J. Roos Intermodaal railvervoer: geen kosteneffectieve milieumaatregel? Een analyse met behulp van reduktiekosten. 30. Dijkstra, A. Ronddraaien of rechtuit rijden? Ruimtelijke structuur van een vervoersysteem voor containers. 31. Dijst, M. Actieruimte als integrale maat voor bereik en mobiliteit. 32. Egeter, B. & L.R. Lutje Schipholt Openbaar vervoer in grote steden: een methodiek voor marktverketing. 33. Erkens, A. & P.H.L. Bovy Eerlijke ruimte, over ruimtebeslag door deelstelsels. 34. Geerlings, H. & Th.J.H. Schoemaker Technologie moet het doen! Pleidooi voor een gestratificeerde aanpak. 35. Goeverden, K. van & B. Egeter Een bouwdoos voor personenvervoersystemen. 36. Govers, B. Regionale spoorlijnen opbouwen of afbreken. 37. Hagen, M. van, J. Reimerink & J. Tils Multimodaal personenvervoer: uitwerking van kansrijke concepten. 445 465 485 503 521 541 5.53 575 589 609 627 641 655 xv

38. Jansen, G.R.M. & J.C. van der Zwart Technologische ontwikkelingen in verkeer en vervoer: aanknopingspunten voor beleid. 39. Jong, G. de, E. Kroes & H. van der Loop THOM: een hulpmiddel bij de keuze van OV-techniek. 40. Jorna, R.A.M., CA. Verweij & H. Speksnijder Kan telematica bijdragen aan de concurrentiekracht van de kustvaart? 41. Korver, W., M. van Hagen & R. Smokers Urban car: vier beleidsscenario s voor een nieuw auto-concept. Dee1 3 42. Kraan, M. Analyse en discussie van een model voor de verdeling van tijd. 43. Kreutzberger, E. Den Haag Centraal Station. Belangenafweging en informatiebehoefte t.a.v. een druk vervoersknooppunt en dynamisch stukje centrum. 44. Mede, P.H.J. van der Moeilijkheden bij de evaluatie van verkeersbeheersingsmaatregelen. 45. Minderhoud, M.M. & P.H.L. Bovy Een dynamisch parkeerreserveringssysteem voor autoluwe birmensteden. 46. Okkema, E., H. van Ever-t & C. Wijnties Het effect van grootschalige geconcentreerde detailhandel (GDV) op de mobiliteit. 47. Peeters, P., Th. Schoemaker & P. Rietveld Mag het ietsje minder hard? Kosten en baten van verlangzaming van het autoverkeer. 48. Renes, G. & 0. Schmidt-Reps Koopkracht- en verdelingseffecten van duurdere mobiliteit. 49. Rienstra, S.A., P. Nijkamp & J.M. Vleugel Beoordeling en presentatie van resultaten van expert-scenario s voor toekomstig duurzaarn personenvervoer. 679 703 721 741 765 787 813 829 849 869 889 905 XVI

50. Rietveld, P., J. Rouwendal & R. Zwier Pendelafstanden en ruimtelijk zoekgedrag op de arbeidsmarkt. 925 5 1. Schol, E. SAVE-Transport, de modellering van energieverbruiksontwikkelingen. 943 52. Schrijnen, P.M. Uitdagingen voor de 2 1 ste eeuw. Vragen over en denkbeelden voor een nieuw infrastructuurbeleid. 963 53. Schrijnen, P.M. & H.G. van de Pol Doelgroepenbeleid: verschil moet er zijn. 981 54. Smits, C., T. van Maanen & G. Borgman De scenarioverkenner na 2 jaar. 1001 55. Spapt, I. & C. Harteveld Vinex-lokaties en verkeer: verkeerskundige verrassing of stedelijke ver as sing. 1021 56. Verweij, C.A., M.A. van den Bossche & T.J.M. Meijer Incomaas: De ruimtelijke effecten van containeroverslagfaciliteiten en infrastructuur op de Maasvlakte. 1031 57. Visser, J.G.S.N. & A.J. van Binsbergen Bereikbaarheid, drie toekomstbeelden voor 2040. 1053 58. Vleugel, J.M. & P. Nijkamp Methoden en toepassing van scenario s in transportonderzoek. 1073 59. Waerden, P. van der, E. Bemards & H. Oppewal Parkeersituatie en de vervoermiddelkeuze van winkelcentrumbezoekers. 1093 60. Wee, B. van 8z T. van der Hoom Reacties van werkenden op bedrijfsverplaatsingen. Resultaten van empirisch onderzoek. 1109 61. Wee, B. van & T. van der Hoom Ruimtelijk gedrag en level-of-service data: netwerk of hemelsbreed? 1127 62. Weijers, S. Tele-shopping. Haar toekomstkansen en haar betekenis voor de gang naar de winked. 1147 XVII

63. Zimmerman, A. & P. de Zoete SVV stad stimuleert duurzaam stedelijk verkeer. 1161 64. Zonnenberg, H.J.M. & K.A. Brohm Waar, waarom en hoeveel transferia in de regio? 1177 65. Zuylen, H. van Van computermodel naar beleidsondersteunend instrument. 1193 Lijst van deelnemers 1209 XVIII

TABLE OF CONTENTS Foreword Table of contents Part 1 1. Aardoom, N., J. van Ginkel & R. Runderkamp PADRE: a system for calculating regional mobility features. 1 2. Bruinsma, F., P. Nijkamp & G. Pepping A benefit assessment of highgrade urban rail infrastructure. 21 3. Buffing, A.H.M. & E.H. Poelstra Can the emperor s new clothes be divided among the regional princes? 41 4. Evert, H.C. van & L.H. Immers Characterization of the regional transport policy. 49 5. Fledderus, K. & M. Vanderschuren Traffic accident risk seems to be lower on Randstad-level. 65 6. Geurs, K. Effects of local traffic and transport policy on intensities and the environment. 87 7. Ginkel, J.C. van, S.P. Berrevoet & C.A.J. Wilbers Decentralised management of main road infrastructure maintenance: implications for knowledge requirements. 107 8. Gommers, M.J.P.F. Accesibility by sea of the Noordzeekanaal-area: Regional and transport economic analyses: a decentralised approach. 121 9. Kapoen, L., J. van Grinsven & J. Hoetelmans Traffic Safety. Regional differences in traffic safety. 135 10. Korbee, H., A. Hoogvorst & K. Kusters Het InfraLab-experiment in Noord-Brabant als marktplaats voor kennisuitwisseling. 153 11. Louisse, K. & H. van der Rest Support bicycle policy at the regional scale with models. 173 XIX

12. Meurs, H., H. Flikkema & J. van der Waard Operationalisatie van bereikbaarheid (OBER). 13. Meurs, H., J. Tils & J. van der Waard Monitoring congestie. 14. Moritz, G., J. van der Waard & J. Exe1 A more powerful mobility survey. 15. Ploeg, G.C.P. van der & F. le Clercq Comprehensive and interactive considerations: new requirements towards policy analyses and decision making regarding infrastructure investments. 16. Rtihl, A. Knowledge shared is knowledge multiplied. 17. Velde, D. van de & W. Veeneman Beste burgemeester, waar gaat deze lijn heen? Een produktie in 8 delen. 18. Witbreuk, M. Collective action and regional transport policy. Part 2 19. Baggen, J.H. Sustainable mobility in the Randstad in 20 15 : A causal path scenario analysis. 20. Beek, P. van, N. Kalfs & M. Speulman Reconstruction of trips in time budget research. 21. Benschop, J., E. van Berkum & L. Schoren Dynamic assignment put into practice. 22. Bilderbeek, R., M. van Hagen & W. Korver Scenarios for chipcard use in traffic and transport systems in the year 2015. 23. Binsbergen, A. van Developments within the transportation system. 24. Binsbergen, A. van & J. Visser Underground distribution in urban areas? 189 211 231 251 267 283 303 323 343 361 383 405 425 xx

25. Boose, J. & B. van Wee Influence of pricing measures on car ownership and use, energy use and emissions. 445 26. Bovy, P.H.L. & M. Tacken Behavioural reactions to traffic congestion. 465 27. Bozuwa, J., M. van den Bossche & A. t Hoen The economic importance of separate lanes for freight in Zuid-Holland. 485 28. Bruinsma, F., A. t Hoen & J. Klooster Manaul for the appraisal of economic effects of infrastructure projects: a new economic evaluation tool. 503 29. Dings, J.M.W. & J.H.J. Roos Intermodal rail transport not a cost effective environmental measure? An analysis by reduction costs. 521 30. Dijkstra, A. Spatial patterns of transport systems for containers. 541 31. Dijst, M. Action space as an integral measure for accessibility and mobility. 553 32. Egeter, B. & L.R. Lutje Schipholt Public transport in large cities: a method for market exploration. 575 33. Erkens, A. & P.H.L. Bovy Fair space, space occupancy by modes. 589 34. Geerlings, H. & Th.J.H. Schoemaker Technology has the power! A plea for a stratified approach. 609 35. Goeverden, K. van & B. Egeter A box of building blocks for passenger transportation systems. 627 36. Govers, B. Build up or pull down regional railways. 641 37. Hagen, M. van, J. Reimerink & J. Tils Multimodal traffic: exploration of promising concepts. 655 XXI

38. Jansen, G.R.M. & J.C. van der Zwart Technological developments in traffic and transport: relevance and options for policy making. 39. Jong, G. de, E. Kroes & H. van der Loop THOM: a tool to aid decision-making on the choice of public transport system. 40. Joma, R.A.M., C.A. Verweij & H. Speksnijder Can the competitive edge of short sea shipping be improved by telematics? 41. Korver, W., M. van Hagen & R. Smokers Urban car: four policy scenarios for a new car concept. Part 3 42. F&an, M. A time allocation model analysed and discussed. 43. Kreutzberger, E. The Hague Central Station. Balancing interests and information demand in regard to a busy transport node and dynamic part of the centre. 44. Mede, P.H.J. van der Complexities of the evaluation of traffic management measures. 45. Minderhoud, M.M. & P.H.L. Bovy A dynamic parking space reservation system for city centres. 46. Okkema, E., H. van Ever-t & C. Wijnties The efffect of large scale concentrated retail trade on mobility. 47. Peeters, P., Th. Schoemaker & P. Rietveld Please, a little slower. Costs and benefits ot the slowing down of car-traffic. 48. Renes, G. 8~ 0. Schmidt-Reps Koopkracht- en verdelingseffecten van duurdere mobiliteit. 49. Rienstra, S.A., P. Nijkamp & J.M. Vleugel Judgement and presentation of results of expert-based scenarios for future sustainable passenger transport. 50. Rietveld, P., J. Rouwendal & R. Zwier Commuting Distances and Spatial Labor Market Search. 679 703 721 741 765 787 813 829 849 869 889 905 925 XXII

51. Schol, E. SAVE-Transport, the modelling of developments in energy use. 52. Schrijnen, P.M. Challenges for the next century. 53. Schrijnen, P.M. & H.G. van de Pol Target group policy: the inevitable distinction. 54. Smits, C., T. van Maanen & G. Borgman De scenarioverkemrer na 2 jaar. 55. Spape, I. & C. Harteveld Vinex locations and traffic: axes in urban traffic planning. 56. Verweij, CA., M.A. van den Bossche & T.J.M. Meijer Incomaas: The spatial effects of container handling facilities and infrastructure at the Maasvlakte. 57. Visser, J.G.S.N. & A.J. van Binsbergen Accessibility, three futures for the year 2040. 58. Vleugel, J.M. & P. Nijkamp Methoden en toepassing van scenario s in transportonderzoek. 59. Waerden, P. van der, E. Bemards & H. Oppewal Parking situation and the choice of transportation mode of shopping centre visitors. 60. Wee, B. van & T. van der Hoom Reactions of workers on firm relocations. Results of empirical research. 61. Wee, B. van & T. van der Hoom Spatial behaviour and level-of-service data: network or airline distances? 62. Weijers, S. Tele-shopping. Haar toekomstkansen en haar betekenis voor de gang naar de winkel. 63. Zimmerman, A. & P. de Zoete SW stad stimuleert duurzaam stedelijk verkeer. 64. Zonnenberg, H.J.M. & K.A. Brohm Transferiums in the Amsterdam region: where, why and how many? 943 963 981 1001 1021 1031 1053 1073 1093 1109 1127 1147 1161 1177 XXIII

65. Zuylen, H. van From computer model to policy support instrument. List of participants 1193 1209 XXIV

A time allocation model analysed and discussed. MariEtte Kraan Universiteit Twente Faculteit Tecbnische Bedrijfskunde Vakgroep Civiele Techniek 15 September 1995 765

Samenvatting... _.............. 2 1 Introduction _................ 3 2 Towards a model specification........ 4 3 Functional Form....... 7 4 Simplified Model....... 12 5 Theoretical Analysis....... 15 6 Conclusions.......... 16 References..... 17 Appendix................... 18 766

Samenvatting Anatyse en discussie van een model voor de verdeling van tijd. Deze paper ontwikkelt en bediscussieerd een model voor de allocatie van tijd aan binnenshuis en buitenshuis activiteiten, inclusief het gegenereerde verkeer. Het model gebruikt nuts maximalisatie technieken, waarbij het nut afhangt van het type, de duur, locatie en frequentie van de activiteiten. De complexiteit van het ontwikkelde model en problemen rond de parameterschatting hebben geleid tot een simplificatie van het model. Dit versimpelde model beschouwd slechts CCn activiteiten-categorie en de afhankelijkheid van de afstand is afgezwakt. We beschouwen twee manieren om de nutsfunctie te definieren en deze worden met elkaar vergeleken. Voor beide model technieken onderzoeken we de gevolgen van verandering van exogene variabelen. Bijvoorbeeld door het totale tijdbudget te verhogen als gevolg van kortere werkweken. Ook de invloed van een grotere gemiddelde snelheid wordt onderzocht. Tot slot wordt de bruikbaarheid van beide versimpelde modeltechnieken besproken. Summary A time allocation model analysed and discussed. This paper develops and analyses a model for time allocation on in-home and out-ofhome activities, including the generated travel. The model uses utility maximisation approach, where the utility depends on activity type, duration, location and frequency of the activity. The complexity of the model and problems with parameter estimation lead to the use of a simplified version of the model. This simplification incorporates one class of out-of-home activity types and the dependency on the location is somewhat weakened. We consider two approaches of defining the utility function, which will be compared. For both model approaches the impact of changes in exogenous variables is analysed. The comparison is made how both models show what happens with the amount of generated travel if the total time budget increases, for example by working less hours. But also the consequences of an increase in average travel speed is analysed. A discussion about the usefulness of this model completes the paper. 767

3 1 Introduction The past decades mobility has grown considerably. Apart from increasing travel distances also the number of trips and travel time has increased (see e.g. Gommers and K&ken, 1992). The question then arises whether this growth will continue or whether there will be some limits to it. And if mobility growth is limited, the question is at what level the limits occur and when they occur. To search for these limits a model is developed which allocates time to various activities, out-of-home as well as in-home and to the generated travel. This paper develops a theoretical framework and gives a model structure (see also earlier papers of author: Kraan, 1994 or 1995). The theory presented here is based on the theory of allocation of time (Becker, 1965; Winston, 1987) combined with aspects of the theory of flexible budgets (Golob et al, 1981; Downes and Emmerson, 1985). Time as well as money will be allocated to various activities and goods, including travel. The allocation is based on utility maximisation, where the utility depends on characteristics of outdoor activities, like priority, duration, location and frequency, the effort of travel, the amount of time spent at home and money spent on consumption goods. Due to the complexity of this model a simplified version is developed, with only one activity type and with fixed unit travel distance. This simplification will help to understand the relationships within the theory. Two modelling approaches, namely with an additive utility function and with a multiplicative utility function, are analysed and compared. For both models we analyse the impact of changes in exogenous variables, such as total time budget, travel speed and unit distance. Finally we draw some conclusions, based on these analyses and discuss the usefulness of both model approaches. Furthermore, we give some recommendations for further research, mainly concerned with extensions of the model and parameter estimation. The contents of this paper is as follows: section 2 describes the assumptions made for developing the model, section 3 gives the complex version of the model, section 4 develops a simplified version, section 5 analyses and compares both simplified model approaches and section 6 gives conclusions and recommendations for further research. 768

4 2 Towards a model specification In this section the assumptions are discussed for the time allocation model. We can make some assumptions on people s behaviour towards activities and travel, necessary for the model specification. First of all, people make decisions on different time horizons; long, medium and short term decisions. In the long term people choose for instance their dwelling location, workplace and employment. Decisions for a medium term can be choices for car ownership, buying a public transport season ticket, club s membership and thus paying a contribution fee. Choices on a short term are made on a daily or weekly basis, like whether or not to go shopping, visiting friends or relatives, going out (to a pub, the cinema, theatre etc.). Since the scope of the model is to aim at long term decisions of how people would divide their time between the various activities, all these decisions are modelled at once, without the distinction between the different time horizons. People have limited amounts of time and money available. These time and money budgets are given by the employment status (working full time, part time or unemployed) and income. Also the amount of sleep (which differs strongly between children, adults, and elderly people for example) affects the time budget. Within these time and money budgets the total activity pattern has to be scheduled. The key question is how these available time and money is divided over the activities. Activity patterns depend on people s life style. This in turn is dependent on various characteristics, such as gender, age, education level, employment and life cycle stage. Different life styles lead in general to different activity patterns. So the allocation of time and money will also be different for various population groups. The population can be divided into homogeneous groups, based on their time and money budgets. On the one extreme we distinguish people with a lot of time but few money, like the unemployed, and on the other extreme people with a lot of money but very few time, like the double income households, where both adults have a full time job. And of course a lot of population groups fall in between these two extremes. We assume that people with comparable budgets and background variables show comparable activity patterns, at least regarding the total time allocated on activities. Behaviour varies more between individuals than between households. The behaviour of the household members is very divers, because within a household the members have different time budgets. So for this reason the model is concerned with individual behaviour. Of course the type of household an individual belongs to is important for his or her behaviour. When examining individuals, for instance housewives, there is a big difference in behaviour dependent on the household characteristics, for example whether there are little children in the household or not. So the household type, or life cycle stage is a very important characteristic in defining population groups. 769

Activities can be undertaken at home or out of home, such that a trip needs to be made. Travel is a demand, derived from activities. The need to perform an activity on a specified location generates travel. For activities with a high priority people do not mind to travel that much, because they have an urgency to get at the desired location. For low priority activities people might reconsider their trip, whether they do want to go that far or whether they want fo go at all. So travel choices do depend on the preferences of activities. This can be interpreted as travel creating some kind of satisfaction, because it gets people to the desired location, to perform an activity. 5 In economic theory this satisfaction is called utility. So the scheduling of activities can be described by micro-economic theories of utility maximisation. This assumes rational behaviour of people. Of course in reality people do not always behave rational, but the outcome of their behaviour can be described by this rationality. The model presented here is based on microeconomic theory of consumer behaviour. All activities performed yield a certain amount of utility. The utility obtained by perfoting an activity depends not only on the type of activity, but also on the duration, the location and the frequency with which the activity is undertaken. Total utility is a function of the utility of each activity, the disutility of travel and the utility of goods purchased. Individuals maximise the utility of their total activity pattern under time and money budget constraints. Activities can be compulsory or discretionary. In our theory activities are placed into three categories: the obligatory activities (labour, study or school attendance), maintenance activities (household tasks, like shopping, or private business) and leisure activities (social and recreation, e.g. sports, visiting friends or relatives, or going out). The reason for this categorisation is given by the characteristics of these activities. For compulsory activities there is no choice in whether or not to perform the activity in the short run and sometimes the duration and frequency are fixed (e.g. labour: if one has a job for eight hours a day, one has no choice in whether to go to work and for how long). Only in the long run one might consider it a choice. One can decide to change the working condition, like working less hours. The same yields for the distance. Long term choices concerning the distance for obligatory activities can be interpreted as moving house or changing job, and thus the distance to the workplace. In case of optional activities it is more obvious that one has a choice in frequency, duration and location, even in the short term. The category of maintenance activities consists of activities that are more or less obligatory, in the sense that they have to be done, but there is a large choice in frequency, location and duration. But the frequency must be larger than zero. For example, one has to do their shopping, but one can choose to go every day, to the lirtle shops nearby, or to go only once a week to the big shopping mall, further away. 770

The utility obtained by the activities depends on their characteristics; type, duration, location and frequency. The longer the duration the more satisfaction one obtains, with decreasing marginal utility. Because people want to spend as much time as they can on various activities, but after a while the extra utility obtained from spending an extra time unit to the activity decreases. 6 The location of an activity is rendered by the distance travelled. The distance has both a positive and a negative valuation (see also Kitamura, 1995). On the one hand, the longer the distance one is willing to travel the more locations one can reach and the higher the chance that one can reach an attractive location satisfying the needs (for a longer distance larger and more exclusive shops are assumed to be reachable). On the other hand the longer the distance the more effort is needed to travel to the location, given by travel time and travel costs. So the satisfaction obtaining from an activity should compensate the effort needed for travel. The interpretation is that people need to spend some effort to obtain a higher utility in the end, than when they would have continued with the previous activity. (See Figure 1.) People will undertake a second activity if the satisfaction of this second activity at least compensates the extra effort for travel to the second location. But after a while the need to spend some time at home will be strong enough to stop outdoor activities and return home. outdoor The utility of an activity also depends on the Time frequency. An activity with high priority will be Figure 1 activiries undertaken more frequently than those with low priority. Some activities performed with a higher frequency obtain more utility, even if the total duration stays the same. For example for leisure activities one yields more satisfaction from performing twice a week one hour than from once a week for two hours. This assumption was also stated by Linder (1971) who expected people to split up their time more and more and thus performing more, but shorter activities. But the higher the frequency, the higher the extra disutility for travel. Obligatory activities (such as labour) have fixed frequencies or at least a minimum value for the frequency, on the short term. Again, for long term decisions the frequency can be taken variable. The contribution of the frequency to the utility differs for different population groups. For example retired people with much leisure time often go out to do some shopping, while people with full time jobs, thus with few leisure time, like to do their shopping only once a week. In-home activities yield a similar utility function, except for the distance travelled; because no trips have to be made for activities at home. All activities at home are considered alike; there is 771

no distinction assumed between the various in-home activities. The model concentrates on out-ofhome activities, as those will generate travel. The time spent at home will be considered as a flexible budget constraint. We assume that everyone wants to spend some time at home, irrespective of the activities undertaken. 7 Also the money available is to be spent on activities, travel and other goods. The amount of goods purchased generate a positive utility. The money available for purchasing goods can be seen as the amount of money not spent on activities and travel, or the money saved. It can be interpreted as a measure of welfare. This measure for goods is considered as the flexible money budget (see Golob et al, 1981; or Downes and Emmerson, 1985). All these assumptions lead to a model, based on micro-economic theories of consumer behaviour to allocate the total time and money available to various activities, at home as well as out-ofhome, including the travel generated by the out-of-home activities. In this model individuals maximise the total utility of their activity pattern, under time and money constraints. The next section develops this model. 3 Functional Form The previous section gave some assumptions the model developed here should comply to. The aim of the model is to allocate the total amount of time and money available to various activities and goods. Activities can be performed in-home, with duration TH, as well as out-of-home, with duration T,. Activities performed out-of-home generate travel over some distance di to reach the desired location. The performance of activities lead to some amount of utility, which is then maxim&d by the individual. The utility of an activity depends on the duration I;, location di and frequencyfi of that activity. This relationship differs of course for different types of activities. Consumer behaviour is considered to be bounded on time and money expenditures. The total time available will be allocated to various activities, both obligatory and discretionary, at home as well as out of home, and to travel. The total amount of money available will be allocated to the activities, travel and other consumption goods. Some activities yield an amount of money, most activities cost an amount of money. These costs can depend on the frequency and duration of the activity and the distance travelled determines the travel costs. 772

The general model structure can now be formulated as: 8 subject to: (1) T,, d:,fi 2 0 vi T,,G 1 0 Here T, d, andf; are the total time spent on, the distance travelled for, and the frequency of activity i, respectively. T,, is the total time spent at home and G the amount of money spent on various goods and services other than travel or out-of-home activities. The average speed is denoted by v,, such that (d,lv,) denotes travel time. The costs going with activity i, c,(t,, d,,x) are divided into the costs of the activity itself and travel costs. The costs of the activity consists of fixed costs r$ (e.g. contribution for a sports club, payed once, independently of the frequency or duration), costs per time of performance ( % (e.g. the price of a ticket for the theatre) and variable costs <.T, (for some recreational activities, e.g. going to a fun-fair, recreational shopping, going to a pub: the longer one stays the more money one spends). Most activities cost an amount of money, so 4 is positive. But the activity labour yields an amount of money; in this case < is negative; so c, = -w.t, + travel costs; with w the wage rate. Travel costs are given by the variable costs per distance travelled cf.d,. The cost function is then defined by c, = cf + cf.t, + c$d, + c$.f;. The budget constraints are given by T,,, the time budget, and I, the money budget. There exists a trade-off between the time and money expenditures through the amount of time spent working, T, (i = work). If the time spent working increases, then the variable income w.t, increases, thus total income increases and more money can be spent on other activities. On the other hand, by working more time, individuals have less time to spend on other activities. Things are easier to see by rearranging the budget constraints and rewriting them as: So an increase in Tw leads to an increase in disposable income, but a decrease in available time. According to Becker (1965) and Winston (1987) the activity itself does not produce a utility, but through performing an activity one obtains a commodity Z, that produces a utility, comparable with production functions (e.g. cooking itself not always provides someone with utility, but the 773

9 I c t?!w + 2 + TH = T,,, - T, & ci(l$dj) + &d, + G I Y + wtw dinner made as a result of cooking yields satisfaction). This production function Z, (or commodity as Becker calls it, or the intensity of the activity, according to Winston) depends on the characteristics of the activity (duration, frequency and distance to the location). Also the time spent at home and the goods purchased generate a similar commodity Z, and Z,, respectively. For travel we obtain a disutility or resistance R;, for all out-of-home activities i. (2) Total utility, U,,,, is now a function of all these commodities and resistances. So ZJ,,, is then the obtained utility for the total activity pattern: U,m = U(Zi,Ri,vi; Z,,Z,) Consider a discretionary outdoor activity i with duration T,, frequency J and distance d, between home and the location of the activity. Now the production function Z, is a function of I;, d, andf;. The form of this production function (the utility of a single activity) is described in 2. A mathematical function that meets the requirements of that form is the Cobb-Douglas function and so the commodity of activity i is given by: Zi(i(r,.di,f;) = Tf.d, -f where pi, yi and p, are parameters with values between 0 and 1. In case there is hardly any choice, i.e. for obligatory activities, the same functional form yields, but with very small parameter values for &, y, and p, (approaching zero), such that Z, is almost constant. But for modelling long term behaviour even obligatory activities can be modelled as being more or less free to choose. The parameters define the relative weight of characteristics r, d, andf;. To reach the location where the activity takes place, the distance d, needs to be travelled. The effort to do so (denoted as resistance or disutility) is defined by total travel time and total travel costs. Travel costs are split into variable costs c$d, and fixed costs p&. The last term is interpreted as starting costs: every time one starts to travel it costs a bit extra. Ten short trips of five kilometres, for example, costs more than one long trip of fifty kilometres. If time is considered more valuable than monetary costs, then the effort caused by travel time (rd,/v,) will be valued more negative than the effort caused by monetary costs (t.(cf.d, + p,,$)). In that case l > t. If on the other hand an individual has plenty of time, but money is scarce < < t. The resistance of travel is given by: 774

10 The quotient l/t denotes the value of travel time. The total time spent on activities at home also contributes to a positive utility, through Z,, as well as the total amount of consumption goods purchased, through Z,. The total time spent at home acts like a constraint on the total time spent out of home. And the amount of goods can be interpreted as a constraint on the costs of outdoor activities and travel. These can be comparable with the flexible budget approach described in Golob ef al (1981) or Downes & Emmerson (1985), where the time not spent on travel (substituted for leisure time) returns in the utility function as a variable, as well as the amotmt of money not spent on travel (see equation (6)). This approach considers utility as a function of travel (the number of kilometres travelled), leisure time and goods purchased. From the viewpoint of travel, leisure time can be seen as the time not spent on travel and the amount of goods purchased is interpreted as the amount of money not spent on travel. Substituting this into the utility function yields: Here x, denotes in the case of the application by Golob et al and Downes and Emmerson the amount of kilometres travelled by mode i. pi denotes unit travel costs, r, unit travel time, f and P are the time and money travel budgets, respectively. cp, $ and x are concave functions. The aim of this model was to allocate time and money to travel; irrespective of the activities. The model developed in this thesis is an extension of the model (6) where the total activity pattern is considered and the distances are only part of the total activity pattern. The time spent on activities at home r,, can be then regarded as the total time not spent on activities out of home including travel time and can be compared with the argument of function x in (6). The goods purchased is regarded as the amount of money not spent on outdoor activities including travel cost and can be compared with the argument of function J, in (6). Since we assume a similar production function for the total time spent at home Z,, compared to out-ofhome activities, and a comparable production function for the purchased goods Z,. we define them by: 775

(7) The utility of the total activity pattern over a period TToT contains the production function of the separate outdoor activities, the resistance of travel, the production function of activities at home and of the consumption goods purchased. There are many ways to define this total utility function. Referring to Winston (1987, pp 570) total utility V, ought to be concave in its arguments. ->o; a%* a2v,,<o a2 3Z2 (8) This could lead to the Cobb-Douglas utility function: V, = [y Z,= (Ti>di.J). @(d,,j)j - Z,?(TH). Z:(G) (9) where all powers (0~ s and T S) lie in the interval ]O,l[. The parameter LY, defines the relative weight of the priority of the activity, so in case of obligatory activities, such as labour, the value of this parameter should be large. But maximising V, gives the same solution as maximising log(u,) and this converts to: There is some trouble with incorporating the resistance of travel R,. This resistance function is linear in the arguments, in stead of concave. Furthermore, using this utility function it is not possible to have a zero solution for one or more of the activities. This means that all activities have to be performed, T,, d, andf; are all > 0. Since the possibility of not performing an activity should be caprured we use another functional form. For this we assume strong separability between the components of the total activity pattern, i.e. there is no substitution between two different, activities from independent classes i andj Cj # i), but the complete categories act as substitutes for one another. Total utility can then be given by: (11) This model is also comparable with the model of daily time allocation to discretionary out-ofhome activities of Kitamura (1984). The main difference is that Kitamura obtains exogenous 776

12 variables as independent variables of the utility function, whereas in this thesis for each population group the model is estimated separately, so the parameters express the exogenous characteristics. The model of Kitamura also includes all kinds of characteristics of obligatory activities, such as distance from home to work and duration of work, whereas the model in this thesis treat them as endogenous variables. Sirnplilied Model Now let us consider some more assumptions on the model to obtain a simplified version of the model given in the previous section. A simplified model gives the opportunity to analyse the model strucmre and the assumptions underlying the model. This can lead to understanding the behaviour of the basic relations in the model. Instead of leaving a choice in the total distance travelled, let us consider the distance constant per activity. So every time an out-of-home activity is undertaken, the location, and thus the distance, is fixed. The total distance is then given by the average distance per activity times the frequency with which the activity is performed. d, = C$. A. The average distance 4 is also called unit travel distance. Furthermore let us consider only one category of all out-of-home activities. So time will be allocated to staying at home, going out, and travel. The model also determines the frequency with which one is going out. The emphasis is on the time allocation, less on money expenditure. Now suppose there is no money constraint and the income is fixed, i.e. not depending on T,, then the costs do not have to be considered. All these assumptions lead to the simplified model: iwar. u, = TB.f + ( T, - T-f?) (12) T.f The time constraint T + f do/v + TH = T, has been substituted (for T,,) in the utility function. Optimising this utility gives us the necessary conditions -=at au, au, af =o (13) This is also a sufficient condition because the utility function considered is concave, i.e. So the solution of (13) will be the maximum of the utility function (12). Solving (13) gives us: 777